checkAd

    target 2 - systemfehler mit fataler wirkung - 500 Beiträge pro Seite

    eröffnet am 01.05.12 18:23:51 von
    neuester Beitrag 23.06.12 12:28:11 von
    Beiträge: 12
    ID: 1.173.995
    Aufrufe heute: 2
    Gesamt: 1.512
    Aktive User: 0


     Durchsuchen

    Begriffe und/oder Benutzer

     

    Top-Postings

     Ja Nein
      Avatar
      schrieb am 01.05.12 18:23:51
      Beitrag Nr. 1 ()
      in den letzten wochen ist ein thema hochgekocht, dass selbst die bundesbank auf den plan gerufen hat: die vollkommen aus den fugen geratenen target2-salden, ein gravierender systemfehler des eurosystems, der den ausgleich von leistungsbilanzdefiziten durch unbesicherte ezb-kredite ermöglicht und durch die kapitalflucht aus den krisenländern (+frankreich!) die ersparnisse des deutschen steuerzahler verpulvert.

      http://blog.handelsblatt.com/handelsblog/2012/03/06/die-myst…

      die bundesregierung kann dieses thema nicht mehr ignorieren und müsste zwingend darauf bestehen, dass ezb-kredite der nationalen notenbanken durch harte assets (wie in amerika) besichert werden bevor der esm installiert wird.
      sollte dieses thema innerhalb der nächsten wochen diskutiert werden, wird es zu heftigen verwerfungen an den kapitalmärkten kommen.

      unter dem oben angegebenen artikel findet sich ein kommentar, der das ganze dilemma auf den punkt bringt:

      Bernd Klehn sagt:
      März 6, 2012 um 2:54 pm

      Eine Währungsunion verträgt dauerhaft keine signifikanten Leistungsbilanzunterschiede und nachfolgende Kapitalflucht aus den Defizitländern, wenn dieses aber auch noch über ein Clearingsystem (Target2) der Währungsunion ermöglicht und gefördert wird, wird es ganz dramatisch. Und diese dramatische Situation haben wir jetzt. Die Eurosystembanker hatten gehofft, wenn man ihnen keine kurzfristige nationale Vorteilsnahme unterstellt, durch reichliches Liquiditätsangebot die Kapitalströme umzukehren und damit die Target2-Salden aufzulösen. Diese Rechnung ist nicht aufgegangen. Seit Juli 2011 erleben wir eine massive Kapitalflucht aus den Krisenländern, die auch nicht durch die 1Billion Langzeittender gestoppt wurden. Die aktuellen Target2-Salden sind Deutschland 547Mrd., Holland 168Mrd. Luxemburg 103, Finnland 45Mrd. Target2 hat somit die Kapitalflucht gefördert und es ermöglicht in den Krisenländern privates durch öffentliches ausländisches zu ersetzen. Das Eurosystem droht an Target2 zu scheitern. Es ist für eine Währungsunion nicht ausreichend bei der Liquiditätszuteilung nur die Geschäftsbanken im Auge zu haben, sondern man muss auch, gerade und besonders die volkswirtschaftlichen Konsequenzen im Auge behalten, sonst sprengt man das Eurosystem.


      anmerkung: die 547 milliarden waren vermutlich zahlen aus dem februar. mittlerweile sind wir bei weit über 600 milliarden euro.

      Forderungen der Bundesbank aus TARGET2
      Betrag: 615.591.527.782,23 Euro (Stand: 31. März 2012)

      http://www.bundesbank.de/target2/target2_saldo.php

      lg max
      Avatar
      schrieb am 01.05.12 18:43:49
      Beitrag Nr. 2 ()
      Hi Max,

      danke für diesen Beitrag. Ich erlaube mir mal, sogar zu sagen, danke "im Namen des Volkes" bzw. des Allgemeinwohls für diesen Beitrag! Auf diese Problematik kann man gar nicht oft genug hinweisen!

      Leider wird meine an solcher Stelle gerne aufkommende Lieblingsfrage wohl nie, bzw. nur von den Gemeinten selbst, beantwortet werden können:

      Sind unsere Politiker Vollidioten oder Verbrecher? Sprich, handeln sie so, wie sie handeln, weil sie es nicht besser wissen oder handeln sie vorsätzlich wider besseren Wissens? :rolleyes:

      LG, tp
      2 Antworten
      Avatar
      schrieb am 01.05.12 19:07:35
      Beitrag Nr. 3 ()
      tradepunk,
      Du musst davon ausgehen, dass unsere Politiker aus beiden Lagern kommen. Die Wortführer sind die, die Du als Verbrecher bezeichnest, wogegen die allermeisten Politiker wohl zu der Gattung zählen, die in Deinen Augen Vollidioten sind, die aber die vorsätzlich kriminellen Handlungen Deiner Verbrecherbande absegnen.
      Avatar
      schrieb am 01.05.12 19:43:15
      Beitrag Nr. 4 ()
      Antwort auf Beitrag Nr.: 43.107.908 von tradepunk am 01.05.12 18:43:49Ist egal: § 17 StGB

      Gilt aber nur für das tumbe Volk, nicht für die Verbrecher mit Immunität.

      Das Beste aber: für die Verbrechen zahlen wir, die Täter verbrigen ihren hochalimentierten Lebensabend frei von Lasten in der Toskana oder sonstwo. ISt das Leben nicht schön?
      Avatar
      schrieb am 02.05.12 09:21:43
      Beitrag Nr. 5 ()
      Antwort auf Beitrag Nr.: 43.107.908 von tradepunk am 01.05.12 18:43:49servus,
      50% idioten, 50% verbrecher und ihre handlanger.
      die verbrecher machen so weiter wie bisher und die idioten sagen sich "augen zu und durch" weil alternativen viel zu anstrengend sind und sie keine ahnung haben.
      schau dir mal den hier an:
      http://www.lobbypedia.de/index.php/J%C3%B6rg_Asmussen
      der bringt mich echt auf die palme. hat ein desaster nach dem anderen zu verantworten und wird mit jeder katastrophe und jetzt ganz nach oben gespült.

      Trading Spotlight

      Anzeige
      Nurexone Biologic
      0,4220EUR +2,93 %
      Die bessere Technologie im Pennystock-Kleid?!mehr zur Aktie »
      Avatar
      schrieb am 02.05.12 09:43:17
      !
      Dieser Beitrag wurde von ArbiMod moderiert. Grund: ANB-widrige Anmeldung
      Avatar
      schrieb am 02.05.12 10:04:00
      Beitrag Nr. 7 ()
      Antwort auf Beitrag Nr.: 43.109.384 von Preisboxer am 02.05.12 09:43:17das ist richtig, dem professor sei dank! aber seitdem haben sich die salden verdoppelt, das problem wird im zusammenhang des esm-vertrages zum absoluten no-go. bundesbank und bundesregierung müssen darauf reagieren, sonst machen sie sich strafbar. es geht de facto um geldwäsche auf unsere kosten.
      oder was machst du, wenn bei dir die bude ausgeräumt wird? zusehen bis nichts mehr da ist? :O

      hier mal die zeitreihe:
      http://www.bundesbank.de/statistik/statistik_zeitreihen.php?…

      und hier der chart:

      :rolleyes:
      Avatar
      schrieb am 02.05.12 10:57:38
      Beitrag Nr. 8 ()
      die Lösung
      ist doch ganz einfach

      kauft Goldmünzen und Silbermünzen

      nur mit Papiergeld
      können euch diese Europa-Finanzabzocker
      in die Armut treiben

      man kann auch in einer Krise Gewinnen
      indem man sein Geld richtig verwaltet

      wer will kann gerne nochmal griechische, portogisische oder
      spanische Staatsanleihen kaufen

      ich empfehle
      Silberanlagen
      bei kleinen Mengen Silberbarren, Silbermünzen
      bei grossen Anlagen
      den Silber-ETF von Sprott (mit physischem Silber gedeckt)
      oder
      den Silber-ETF der Züricher-Kantonal-Bank
      1 Antwort
      Avatar
      schrieb am 02.05.12 12:29:51
      Beitrag Nr. 9 ()
      Antwort auf Beitrag Nr.: 43.109.768 von keepitshort am 02.05.12 10:57:38wenn uns die eurozone um die ohren fliegt, sollte man vielleicht besser spirituosen kaufen. :keks:

      http://www.atimes.com/atimes/Global_Economy/NE02Dj02.html


      THE BEAR'S LAIR
      Euro nears its blow-up point
      By Martin Hutchinson

      With the French election's first round and the revelations about the Target-2 payments system, the euro's prognosis worsened sharply this week. Having generally been a supporter of the euro, provided Britain didn't have to join, I now think flaws in its design and poor policy choices have made it a disaster in waiting.

      Markets were calm this week, with the euro seeming to drift majestically and untroubled through the ether. However, in its current state it resembles nothing more than the ill-fated German airship LZ-129 Hindenburg, silently approaching its terrible destiny above the Lakehurst, New Jersey, Naval Air Station, 75 years ago next Sunday. Oh the humanity, indeed!

      For those not around in 1937, or even for the inaccurate disaster movie of 1975, the Hindenburg was a German passenger airship, no less than 245 meters long (and 41 meters broad, thus larger



      than the 268 meters x 28 meters RMS Titanic) designed to carry 72 passengers at a top speed of 137 kilometers and hour on long ocean journeys to North and South America. With an aluminum frame and coated cotton outer skin, the airship was for political reasons (Britain, the world's main supplier of helium, embargoed its export to Nazi Germany) filled with flammable hydrogen.

      The Hindenburg carried out 63 successful flights in 1936-1937, including 18 roundtrip crossings to North and South America, before bursting into flames while mooring to an airship mast in Lakehurst, NJ on May 6, 1937.

      Sabotage by anti-Nazi groups was alleged but never proved; the most likely explanation for its fate is a hydrogen leak, lit by a spark of static electricity and combusting both the hydrogen and the highly flammable airship outer skin. The leak may have been caused by failure of the light but enormous structure after the very tight double turn undertaken by Captain Max Pruss in the approach.

      Unlike the Hindenburg, which even with a stronger frame and helium was commercially doomed once the passenger aircraft industry got going a few years later, the euro could have worked if it had been properly designed. The Maastricht Criteria recognized the problem when states ran prolonged budget deficits, but they needed to be well enforced, which they were not. Even without the Maastricht Criteria however, market mechanisms exist to preserve a multinational currency bloc against moderate strains.

      In particular, interest rates should have worked to bring the eurozone's economies closer together through the correspondent banking system. When a depositor moves a US$1 million deposit from an Alabama bank to a bank in New York, no currency generally changes hands. Instead the New York bank credits the customer with $1 million and debits the Alabama bank with $1 million under its correspondent banking line.

      If a number of depositors do likewise, the liability of the Alabama bank to the New York bank builds up. Eventually, when the liability gets close to the New York bank's pre-established interbank line of credit for the Alabama bank, the Alabama bank is forced to borrow some money elsewhere (possibly from the Fed) and send it to the New York bank, paying down its interbank line of credit.

      This simple mechanism has a number of economic effects. If Alabama has a persistent trade deficit with New York, payments are made frequently from Alabama banks to New York banks. If Alabama's overall trade is in balance, so that it is in surplus with Texas, say, then the Alabama banks simply transfer money they receive from Texas banks to their accounts with New York banks, and there is no effect on local money market conditions. However, if Alabama runs an overall balance of payments deficit then there is an overall flow of money out of the state's banks. Pretty soon, Alabama banks have to raise their deposit rates to attract additional funds.

      To conserve funds further, they reduce their lending to local businesses, which consequently suffer a rise in interest rates on their borrowings and a decline in their availability. Any lending bubble, in real estate or elsewhere, or any profligacy by the Alabama state government is thus corrected by the market.

      Once the euro had been established, the same should have happened within the eurozone. As Greece and Spain ran balance of payments deficits and Germany ran a surplus, the Bank of Piraeus and Banco Santander would continually have been making payments to Deutsche Bank and Commerzbank. Eventually, as Greek and Spanish payments deficits grew, interest rates in those countries should have risen and credit should have been choked off.

      With the euro having been established in 1999, and Greece and Spain becoming steadily more uncompetitive against Germany, and Greece in addition running a substantial hidden budget deficit, by 2004 or 2005, interest rates in Greece and Spain should have been sharply higher than in Germany, choking off the Spanish housing bubble and maybe restraining the follies of even successive Greek governments.

      I have to say it was a surprise to me at the time that this didn't happen. European Union (EU) bureaucrats pontificated pompously of the glories of "convergence" between the various eurozone economies, but it seemed to me that no such "convergence" in their interest rates should have taken place, because the countries had very different credit risks.

      If Italy borrowed at a 1% higher rate than Germany in the dollar market before the euro's advent, it should still borrow at a 1% higher rate than Germany in the new euro market. Italy is no more able to print euros on its own than dollars, and hence credit spreads between the members of the eurozone should have remained much as they were before the euro's advent (absent massive transfer programs between the eurozone countries, which had, it appeared, between definitively ruled out).

      This did not happen. Yield differentials between German bunds and Spanish, Italian and even Greek government bonds converged within a year of the euro's formation (or in Greece's case, its 2001 entry into the eurozone). By 2005-06, there was no more than 30 basis points (0.3%) difference between German government bonds and Spanish, Italian and even Greek government bonds.

      In retrospect, this should have aroused my suspicions (and those of other intelligent observers) much more strongly than it did. Even in the carefree, liquidity-sloshing days of 2005-06, the differential between Aaa and Baa credit yields averaged around 100 basis points. Greek government bonds should have exhibited at least this differential over German bonds.

      The reason for the mysterious disappearance of credit differentials between northern and southern Europe is now clear - it is the Target (and, from 2007, Target-2) EU payments system. Under these systems, when a Greek makes a large euro payment to a German, his Greek bank makes a payment to the Greek central bank, which makes a payment to the Bundesbank, which pays the German bank, which pays the German.

      This is quite different to the US system. There is no central bank of Alabama intermediating dollar payments between Alabama and New York, and there was equally no need for such intermediation in the eurozone - it just gave the otherwise redundant national central banks something apparently useful to do.

      Under this system, if there's a big trade imbalance between the two countries, then gradually an imbalance grows up between the central banks: the Bank of Greece owes the Bundesbank more and more money. Even more serious, when Greek citizens rush to get their money out of Greek banks and put it in German banks, every million euros by which the Greek citizens reduce their Greek bank risk, breathing sighs of relief, is a million euros by which the Bundesbank increases its exposure to the Bank of Greece.

      According to financial consultant David Marsh, writing in CBS Marketwatch, the Bundesbank's net Target-2 assets have ballooned to 615 billion euros (US$800 billion) in March 2012, while the Banco de Espana's net liabilities rose to 252 billion euros and the Banca d'Italia's to 270 billion euros. Thus the Bundesbank has taken on around $800 billion of credit risk against the weaker economies of Europe.

      A group of German citizens is suing the Bundesbank to force it to wind down its positions in the Target-2 system. Since the obligation built up, doubtless requiring taxpayer bailout at some stage, is some $10,000 for every German man, woman and child, the lawsuit seems entirely justified and indeed overdue.

      If you read the Wikipedia article on Target-2, it's full of pious stuff about "Supporting the implementation of the Eurosystem's monetary policy and the functioning of the euro money market; minimizing systemic risk in the payments market; increasing the efficiency of cross-border payments in euro."

      In reality what Target and Target-2 did was take the credit monitoring out of the system. By giving national central banks something to do and allowing them to deal with each other, it allowed the system to pretend that euro-zone central banks would never default and that payment imbalances were not a problem.

      The credit risks of the payments system, which would have been handled by the banking system, were transferred to central banks and allowed to grow to their current monstrous size. And the normal local money tightening that would have been generated by persistent payment imbalances never happened, so Greek overspending and Spanish dodgy real estate loans grew unchecked and the natural interest differentials between the better and worse euro-zone credits were artificially suppressed.

      The Target-2 payments system is thus the hydrogen in the Hindenburg, the politically motivated flaw in the system that causes disaster. Because it was filled with hydrogen not helium, the Hindenburg burst into flames. Because the euro-zone payments system is routed unnecessarily through central banks, the normal safety features of a single-currency multinational economy were disabled.

      The Spanish real estate boom, the Irish real estate and banking bubble and Greek government dishonesty and profligacy would have caused interest rates in those countries to rise, gently at first and then increasingly sharply as Spanish and Irish real estate companies and the Greek government found their normal sources of credit cut off.

      By bursting bubbles and righting imbalances several years earlier, a properly structured euro would have prevented the gigantic crashes and defaults that have subsequently occurred.

      There have been other mistakes made since, of course. In particular, Greece should have been forced out of the euro as soon as its false accounting was discovered, since no amount of austerity is sufficient to force Greek living standards down to their proper market-clearing level, about half or less of their unjustified peak.

      By keeping Greece in the eurozone, forcing large losses on its innocent private creditors, and giving it a wholly unjustified bailout from its EU partners, the EU authorities have fatally weakened the euro itself, making it vulnerable to adverse political winds. Should Francois Hollande win the French presidential election run-off on May 6, the adverse political winds will be blowing a gale.

      Not only did the Target-2 system cause the initial mess by short-circuiting the market's normal safety mechanisms, the gigantic imbalances it has built up will prevent the problem being "kicked down the road" any further.

      German taxpayers alone have a contingent liability on southern Europe through the payments system that is as large as the maximum agreed bailout fund. This will make it politically impossible for the EU political class to rescue the rotten euro system yet again when the next inevitable minor crisis occurs.

      The euro will then collapse, causing a disaster spectacle that to observers will be as emotionally wrenching as that of the dying Hindenburg. Like the Hindenburg disaster, the euro disaster will have been entirely avoidable.

      For the euro, the fault will lie with the unaccountable EU political class, which has persistently thought itself superior to the market and has attempted to thwart its workings. What is truly shocking is that this tendency did not manifest itself only in the Greek bailout, the type of economic disaster in which governments are inevitably tempted to throw around taxpayer money and shift costs to the private sector.

      It was also apparent in the initial design of the euro at a time of calm prosperity, which allowed too many countries with weak economies and poor governance to be included without corrective mechanisms for their follies.

      Above all it was apparent in the Target/Target-2 payments system, which was specifically designed to thwart the market's natural corrective mechanisms of localized high interest rates and a credit squeeze when bubbles occur or governments overspend. This was not an innocent mistake; to the system's designers, its overriding of market mechanisms was a feature, not a bug.

      When the euro collapses, the EU political class will no doubt blame those sinister forces, the speculators of Anglo-Saxon finance. In reality, the blame will be entirely theirs, and it is to be hoped that the criminal justice system extracts the appropriate penalties in the form of lengthy terms of imprisonment.

      Martin Hutchinson is the author of Great Conservatives (Academica Press, 2005) - details can be found on the website www.greatconservatives.com - and co-author with Professor Kevin Dowd of Alchemists of Loss (Wiley, 2010). Both are now available on Amazon.com, Great Conservatives only in a Kindle edition, Alchemists of Loss in both Kindle and print editions.

      (Republished with permission from PrudentBear.com. Copyright 2005-12 David W Tice & Associates.)
      Avatar
      schrieb am 14.05.12 18:34:21
      Beitrag Nr. 10 ()
      Forderungen der Bundesbank aus TARGET2
      Betrag: 644.182.010.456,05 Euro (Stand: 30. April 2012)

      http://www.bundesbank.de/target2/target2_saldo.php
      Avatar
      schrieb am 09.06.12 12:57:13
      Beitrag Nr. 11 ()
      target2salden im mai

      700.000.000.000,00 € die wir niemals wieder sehen werden.

      http://www.querschuesse.de/stoppt-endlich-den-wahnsinn-targe…

      und es ist fußball.. :cry:
      Avatar
      schrieb am 23.06.12 12:28:11
      Beitrag Nr. 12 ()
      Forderungen der Bundesbank aus TARGET2: 698.567.101.301,00 Euro
      (Stand: 31. Mai 2012)
      http://www.bundesbank.de/Navigation/DE/Service/Services_Bank…


      Beitrag zu dieser Diskussion schreiben


      Zu dieser Diskussion können keine Beiträge mehr verfasst werden, da der letzte Beitrag vor mehr als zwei Jahren verfasst wurde und die Diskussion daraufhin archiviert wurde.
      Bitte wenden Sie sich an feedback@wallstreet-online.de und erfragen Sie die Reaktivierung der Diskussion oder starten Sie
      hier
      eine neue Diskussion.
      target 2 - systemfehler mit fataler wirkung